CIVITAS BACKGROUND BRIEFING
RESPONSE TO TONY BLAIRS
FIRST SPEECH ON IMMIGRATION
By Anthony Browne, Author of the Civitas book Do We
Need Mass Immigration?
The government needs to accept and take into account
the negative economic consequences of immigration
when setting immigration policy, rather than only considering
the positive ones. Otherwise Britain will not get the immigration
policy that best serves its interests.
"The great enemy of the truth
is very often not the lie - deliberate, contrived, and dishonest
- but the myth - persistent, persuasive and unrealistic.
Too often we hold fast to the cliches of our forebears.
We subject all facts to a prefabricated set of interpretations.
We enjoy the comfort of opinion without the discomfort of
thought"
President John F. Kennedy speaking to Yale University, 1962.
Immigration policy has been
captured by special interests who peddle the notion that
immigration is an unmitigated benefit to the nation and
that it is costless. Nothing could be further from the truth.
The immigration myth is based on the premise that attention
need only be paid to the benefits while the costs can be
totally ignored. Only with respect to the formulation of
immigration policy is such nonsense tolerated as conventional
wisdom.
Vernon Briggs, Professor of Industrial and Labor Relations,
Cornell University, giving evidence to the Immigration Subcommittee
of the U.S. House Committee of the Judiciary, 1999
THE FOUR FACTS
The Prime Ministers speech to the Confederation of
British Industry on 27th April 2004 was his first major
speech on immigration, where he accepted the legitimacy
of much public concern about abuse of the immigration system.
But he then set out the case for the governments policy
of actively encouraging mass immigration to the UK. He justified
it on the basis of long discussion, which he boiled down
to four facts in addition to a claim
that Britain had to have immigration because of the high
level of vacancies. All the facts are either outright misleading,
or at best highly contentious. But first we start with Tony
Blairs main claim.
The main claim:
There are half a million
vacancies in our job market, and our strong and growing
economy needs migration to fill these vacancies
According to National Statistics, there were 591,500
job vacancies in the three months to March 2004. But that
was almost exactly the same level as March 2002, and equates
to just 2.3 vacancies per 100 employee jobs, a rate consistent
with the churn as people leave jobs when they
move to another one, rather than evidence of unfilled long
term vacancies. It is impossible to achieve zero vacancies,
which would imply a static economy with no one changing
jobs and no jobs being created and destroyed.
The number of vacancies is also small compared to the number
of people available to work in the UK. Officially, according
to the governments preferred definition of unemployment
(the International Labour Organisation definition, measured
through the Labour Force Survey), there are 1.426 million
unemployed, two and a half times the number of vacancies.
In addition to the 1.4 million officially unemployed,
there are 7.7 million people of working age classified as
economically inactive, neither working nor looking
for work, including 3.0 million men. Of these 7.74 million
economically inactive, 2.06 million want a job but for a
variety of reasons arent looking.
In other words, although the UK has 591,500 vacancies,
there are 3.49 million adults of working age not working
who want a job or very nearly six people (5.89) out
of work wanting a job for every single vacancy.
This is consistent with the Confederation of British Industrys
latest industrial trends survey (April 2004), which showed
that just 10 % of manufacturers said a shortage of skilled
labour affected output, and 3 % said shortages of other
(semi skilled and unskilled) was a constraining factor.
In other words, 90 % of British manufacturers can get as
much skilled labour as they need, and 97 % can get as much
unskilled and semiskilled labour as they need.
The government may be proud of its record on official unemployment,
but Britain suffers far higher levels of hidden unemployment
than other countries. One in four men between the ages of
50 and 65 - nearly 1.3 million people - are economically
inactive, often involuntarily prematurely retired. The proportion
of men aged between 55 and 64 in employment has fallen from
71.5 % in 1983 to 63.3 % in 2000. Anti-ageism campaigners
insist that enabling these people to work often highly
skilled and experienced - would more than fill any labour
market shortages in the UK. Pension experts also insist
that getting these people to work is essential to pay for
our increasing life-expectancy.
There are now 2.7 million people out of work and on sickness
or disability benefits with no obligation to look for work,
even though many are perfectly capable of work. The government
now accepts that this is a vast pool of hidden unemployment.
A recent parliamentary answer revealed that two high profile
government schemes had simply shifted 160,000 job seekers
on to other forms of benefits.
When you take into account the hidden unemployment, Britains
labour market is only performing at the European average.
The TUC estimates that 11.5 % of those of working age want
a job in the UK, the same as the EU average, and actually
higher than other countries that the Prime Minister claimed
had higher unemployment than Britain, including Germany
(11.4%) and France (9.8 %).
The official unemployment rate is 4.8 % of the workforce
in the UK, but only in Britain, with its long history of
high unemployment, would the government consider unemployment
of 4.8 % is full employment. The Trades Union
Congress considers full employment closer to 3%, similar
to the levels in the 1950s and 60s before the oil shock
of 1973. UK official unemployment is higher than many European
countries such as Austria and the Netherlands, and similar
to Japan, which is fretting about mass unemployment, and
not much lower than the US, where there are widespread complaints
of a jobless recovery.
When Labour was elected in 1997, it repeatedly highlighted
a new measure of unemployment which it claimed showed the
social impact of joblessness under the Conservative government
the number of jobless households where
no one is working. This stood at 3.12 million, or 16.8%
of all working age households in Autumn 1998, when the Office
for National Statistics first started measuring it. The
latest figures, Autumn 2003, shows that the number of jobless
households stands at 2.98 million or 15.6% of all working
age households an insignificant decline. By Labours
own favourite measure of the impact of unemployment, Britain
is almost as blighted now as it was when Labour came to
power. If this measure of unemployment was a problem then,
it is still a problem now. It would be interesting to see
Mr Blair explain to people in those workless households
why Britain needs record levels of immigration to fill jobs
that are otherwise unfillable.
Labour also liked to highlight the huge number of children
growing up in workless households, without a role model
to educate them about the world of work . In Autumn 1998,
2.1 million children, 17% of the total, were growing up
in workless households. It is now 1.8 million children,
or 15% of the total, a marginal decrease. Again, if children
living in workless households was a problem when labour
were elected, it is still a major problem now.
Particular groups suffer disproportionately. School leavers,
age 16 and 17, suffer unemployment of 21.1 %, while 18 to
24 year old men suffer unemployment of 11.3 %. Only 58 %
of ethnic minorities of working age have a job, compared
to the national average of 74.9 %.
Over 30 % of black African households are workless, as
are a quarter of Bangladeshi and Pakistani households. Some
regions suffer particularly badly, particularly those areas
that Labour insist are most in need of immigration. London,
where most migrants come, is supposedly in greatest need
of workers, and yet there is already a vast surplus of labour
in London. Far from having full employment, the capital
is the UKs unemployment blackspot, with unemployment
of 6.8 %, the highest of any region of the country, higher
than Northern Ireland, Scotland or the North East of England.
In six London boroughs (Tower Hamlets, Southwark, Newham,
Lewisham, Haringey, and Hackney), unemployment is over 10
%.
There is also startlingly high economic inactivity in London
people neither working nor looking for work, and
so who dont officially count as unemployed. Nearly
1.2 million people in London are of working age but not
working. Across the country as a whole, 21.9 % of people
of working age are neither working nor looking for work,
but it rises to over 30 % in Hackney, Haringey, Newham,
Tower Hamlets, Kensington and Chelsea and Westminster.
The governments encouragement of mass immigration
also indirectly increases the total benefits bill it must
pay. Millions of British workers are on means-tested benefits
which supplement their low incomes, such as housing benefit,
income support, working families tax credit and council
tax benefit. Since reliance on immigration has the effect
of suppressing wages (see below), it means that more workers
rely on these benefits than would otherwise be the case.
If the labour market were allowed to operate freely, rather
than being undermined by the governments immigration
policy, then wages would rise faster, which would take more
of the low paid off in-work benefits. Allowing the labour
market to operate freely would also help draw disadvantaged
workers, such as ethnic minorities, the young, single parents
and the over-50s, into the world of work by giving them
greater opportunities, and denying companies the easier
option of importing workers from overseas. Industry has
an important social role in helping bring disadvantaged
workers into the labour market, but this is undermined by
the governments open door immigration policy. Put
simply, few things would encourage a young long term unemployed
ethnic minority man into the mainstream of society than
the availability of reasonally well-paid jobs and the eventual
prospect of promotion. If all he can get are jobs paying
close to the minimum wage, it makes economic sense to claim
benefits and seek unofficial ways of making money.
Blair Fact 1:
the movement of people and
labour into and out of the UK is, and always has been, absolutely
essential to our economy.
Those who wish to justify the history unprecedented levels
of immigration into the UK often like to claim that it is
just history as normal. Mr Blairs historical assertion
is so simplistic it immediately invites an equally simplistic
response: were the Viking raids of the eight and ninth centuries
AD, which destroyed communities, interrupted trade and decimated
agriculture, really absolutely essential to our economy?
He mentioned the benefits that many refugees brought, from
the French Huguenot in the 17th century to Polish fighters
in the Second World War, but even accepting the contributions
these people undoubtedly made, that cannot be used to justify
actively encouraging immigration on the current scale. The
fact is that through most of its history, the contribution
of immigrants has been marginal, if only because until recently
the scale of immigration has been marginal. Britain became
the first industrial country in the world, and became the
largest economic power in the world in the nineteenth century,
in the almost complete absence of immigration to these isles.
Historically Britain has been a country of emigration not
immigration, founding the US, Canada, Australia and New
Zealand. Nor is the UK unique in its historic non-reliance
on immigration.
Japan became the worlds second largest economy after
the second world war in the almost total absence of immigration,
while Norway became the country with the highest quality
of life in the world (according to the UN) with almost no
immigration. South Korea has been performing an economic
miracle with virtually no immigration, while China is terrifying
the west by being the worlds most economically dynamic
country, despite its almost complete lack of immigration.
Mr Blair failed to mention that for only about 20 years
after the Second World War - out of the last 2000
years has the UK had a policy of actively encouraging mass
primary immigration. At all other times, the policy has
been one of letting in refugees and family members on humanitarian
grounds, as well as a relatively small number for meeting
specific skills shortages. Mr Blairs policy of actively
encouraging mass primary immigration is a historical anomaly.
For the first time in modern history, immigration is increasing
the population of the UK.
Mr Blair highlighted the contributions of immigrants from
South Asia who helped the 1950s economic boom. What
he failed to mention is that many of these were recruited
to the textiles industries of Britains northern towns
that were trying to compete on the basis of low wages with
textiles companies in Asia. They failed, and they are now
almost all closed, leaving as their legacy the alienated
Bangladeshi and Pakistani communities they imported languishing
in poverty and unemployment in seriously socially divided
towns. On any economic assessment, the immigration policy
was a failure.
Britain can never compete on the basis of low wages with
low cost countries such as China for the simple reason that
the cost of living is so much higher, and it is a mistake
to try. Although cheap labour immigration may have staved
off the demise of those industries for a short while, it
also compromised them by encouraging them to go down the
cheap labour route, and discouraging them from going up
the high productivity/value added route (such as designer
clothes and mechanising), which was their only chance of
competing with Asia. In this sense, the cheap labour immigration
policy actually helped ensure their long-term demise.
While mentioning the positive economics aspects of immigration
which certainly exist Mr Blair failed to balance
that with any consideration of the negative consequences:
worse employment opportunities and wages for vulnerable
workers, particularly the unskilled, reduced labour productivity,
reduced incentives to train native workers, greater economic
inequality, greater congestion and exacerbated housing shortages.
Lord Richard Layard, the co-director of the Centre for
Economic Performance at the London School of Economics,
and the mastermind of Labours welfare to work programme,
has written:
'There is a huge amount of evidence
that any increase in the number of unskilled workers lowers
unskilled wages and increases the unskilled unemployment
rate. If we are concerned about fairness, we ought not to
ignore these facts. Employers gain from unskilled immigration.
The unskilled do not.'
The Home Office commissioned an econometric research study
(The local labour market effects of immigration in
the UK Home Office online report 06/03) on the effects
of immigration, and it found: The effect of immigration
on unemployment is positive and statistically significant
(ie immigration pushes up unemployment). It even measured
the scale of the effect: An increase in immigration
amounting to one % of the non-immigrant population would
lead, according to this result, to an increase of 0.18 percentage
points in the non-immigrant unemployment rate. This
government research implies that in the UK, with immigration
amounting to around 10% of the work force, unemployment
would be 3 %, which really is close to full employment,
rather than 5%.
In fact, the government implicitly accepts that immigration
hurts the labour market prospects of those already here,
otherwise it would not require employers to advertise a
job in the UK before they are allowed to import workers
from outside the EU. Recently, because of the impact that
having open immigration of IT workers was having on native
IT workers, the government scrapped the fast-track visa
system for the sector. Recently, the Home Secretary David
Blunkett said that he wouldnt be encouraging so much
immigration to Britain if unemployment were higher than
it is. Though they refuse to explicitly accept the labour
market consequences of immigration, they do accept them
implicitly.
As Lord Layard implied, there is overwhelming evidence
that the laws of supply and demand are not miraculously
suspended when it comes to the effects of immigration on
wages. Professor George Borjas of Harvard University, a
Cuban refugee to the US who is widely regarded as the worlds
greatest immigration economist (and author of the main US
government report in the last thirty years on immigration),
recently conducted the most detailed study yet carried out
on the impact of immigration on wages (The Labor Demand
Curve is Downward Sloping: Re-examining the impact of immigration
on the labour market, National Bureau of Economic
Research, June 2003). It concluded that in the US: immigration
has substantially worsened the labour market opportunities
faced by many native workers. He found that immigration
in the US has reduced wages of the average worker by 3.2%,
rising to 8.9% for high school drop outs. His overall conclusion
was that: The analysis indicates that immigration
lowers the wage of competing workers: a 10% increase in
supply reduces wages by 3 to 4%.
In London, where most immigrants come, we may already be
seeing these effects in the areas that immigrants most usually
work. According to Income Data Services, shelf-fillers in
shops now earn 10 % less in London, which has a huge pool
of cheap immigrant labour, than the national average. Chains
such as McDonalds and Burger King, which have previously
always had their highest pay rates in central London, now
pay higher rates in places outside London than they do in
London. This is good if you like cheap big Macs in central
London, but not good if these are the sort of jobs you are
competing for.
It is not just the unskilled who could be affected. The
Chartered Institute for Personnel and Development issued
a report on April 30th 2004, the day before 8 eastern European
countries joined the EU, warning that
Highly skilled, English-speaking job applicants from
accession states could reduce pay rates. UK salaries for
white-collar professionals such as lawyers and accountants
could be driven down by European enlargement.
Relying on cheap labour imports to boost the economy can
also have the effect of reducing productivity, by discouraging
companies from mechanising or investing in the training
of their personnel. The worlds most revered central
banker, Alan Greenspan, Chairman of the US Federal Reserve,
gave testimony to the U.S. Senate last year:
Although discovery of new technologies
is to some degree a matter of luck, we know that human activities
do respond to economic incentives. A relative shortage of
workers should increase the incentives for developing labor-saving
technologies and may actually spur technological development.
Economic historians have argued that one reason that the
United States surpassed Great Britain in the early nineteenth
century as the leader in technological innovation was the
relative scarcity of labor in the United States. Patent
records of this period show that innovation did respond
to economic incentives and that the scarcity of labor clearly
provided incentives to develop new methods of production.
Mr Blair mentioned a Treasury analysis that the economic
growth rate would be 0.5 % less if migration ceased for
the next two years. Immigration certainly does increase
GDP because the more people there are working, the more
the economic output will be, but most of the increase in
GDP goes to the immigrants themselves. What matters to native
workers is not GDP, but GDP per capita: they dont
care how big the economy is, but how rich they are. A US
government study found that while immigration had increase
the US GDP by $200bn a year, actually only between $1bn
and $10bn of this went to the workers already in the US,
a trivial amount compared to the $8,000 bn US economy, with
the rest going in pay to the immigrants themselves. In total,
immigration only increased US GDP growth by 0.1 per cent
a year, a trivial amount.
As Martin Wolf, the chief economic commentator of the
Financial Times wrote on the 13th April 2004: In a
competitive economy the gains from migration should largely
accrue to migrants themselves, leaving little over for the
recipient community. In theory, the latter will enjoy an
economic surplus. But this is likely to be small.
He concluded: one's assessment of the desirability
of sizeable immigration is a matter more of values than
of economics. It is not a choice between wealth and poverty,
but of the sort of country one desires to inhabit.
It is a matter of both common sense and academic analysis
that immigration at the current rate to the UK, of around
200,000 people a year, has an impact on the housing market,
increasing shortages and pushing up rents and house prices,
and thus reducing labour mobility. By boosting the population,
it also increases congestion on roads and public transport,
exacerbating the shortage of land for factories and offices,
further damaging the economy. In compensation, the economies
of scale of increasing the population through increasing
the size of the domestic market are marginal in an open
trading economy like the UK.
Having a policy of population growth can make economic
sense in sparsely populated lands where a critical mass
of humanity is needed for a certain level of infrastructure
such as roads, as well as to develop sufficient local markets
for certain goods and services that cannot be delivered
long distance. But population growth can be economically
damaging for a highly densely populated country already
suffering from congestion costs, with land shortages acting
as a constraint on business. The US economist Julian Simon
of the Cato Institute, a very high profile advocate of mass
immigration, conducted a study in 1989 to prove his thesis
that a greater population led to greater GDP per capita
across a range of countries, but was forced to concede that
he could find no such correlation.
Although the problems of housing shortage and congestion
are of acute concern to the British public, the government
showed its obliviousness to this aspect when the Home Secretary
David Blunkett declared there was no obvious upper
limit to the number of immigrants the UK should admit.
Ignoring any of the negative consequences of the immigration,
as this government persistently does, means that it is unable
to formulate an optimum immigration policy, which necessarily
means striking a balance between the positive aspects with
the negative ones, and between the winners from immigration
(generally those who employ immigrants) with the losers
(generally those who compete with immigrants). As Vernon
Briggs of Cornell University testified to the US Congress:
The "costs" of immigration
need to be taken into account as much as do the "benefits"
when it comes to designing the appropriate policy. The concerns
of the "losers" are as relevant as those of the
"winners." Such is especially the case when those
most adversely impacted are the least advantaged persons
in the population and labor market.
The International Labour Organisations paper on migration,
Migration for all: towards a new paradigm for migrant
labour, said:
In the understandable enthusiasm
to open borders to eager workers, unrealistic claims have
been trumpeted, corners have been cut, and foreseeable difficulties
have received inadequate attention. As such, many of the
problems created by migrant worker programmes have occurred
as consequences which were either unintended or unacknowledged
by the proponents and architects of these policies.
Blair Fact 2:
The country is already highly
selective about who is allowed in to the UK to work, study
or settle
The Prime Minister is keen to reassure those who worry
that immigration is out of control, by saying that almost
220,000 people were refused entry clearance into the UK
in 2002 three times the rate of 1992. But immigration
has increased a similar amount, so the level of selectiveness
is almost unchanged.
However, he didnt mention that the government has
a target of issuing 200,000 work permits to non-EU citizens
every year, and that it has another target of processing
90% of those applications for work permits within 24 hours
of receiving them. Needless to say, processing them in such
short time means that virtually no checks are being done
on either whether the applicant or their claimed qualifications
are genuine, or whether the employers need is genuine.
The lack of not just controls but elementary inspection
of language schools which are free to import
for profit as many students as they like has been a notorious
loophole for years which the government has just announced
an intention to consider some measures to close it. Registry
officers claim that one in five marriages in London is a
commercial scam in order to obtain UK citizenship, which
hardly suggests that the UK is highly selective.
In contrast, in countries of immigration such as Canada
and Australia, there are very tight controls on language
schools and marriages, with far tighter criteria for admission
in the first place. It is far easier for a British person
to import a spouse than it is for a Canadian citizen to
import one.
Mr Blair wistfully says that anyone being admitted to the
UK to work or study must satisfy our overseas embassies
that they will leave the UK at the end of their stay.
Unfortunately for Mr Blair, UK embassies do not possess
fully functioning crystal balls. Unfortunately also, the
government has absolutely no way of knowing whether those
that it lets in to Britain do actually leave: the abolition
of immigration exit controls means that it is actually impossible
to tell whether someone has left the country or not. This
is in stark contrast to, for example, the US and Australia
where whenever visitors enter or leave the country, they
have their passports entered into a computer, which automatically
flags up if they overstay their visa and then automatically
imposes sanctions on them if they overstay, such as not
being allowed back into the country for ten years. Since
it is impossible for the government to catch visa-overstayers,
it is impossible for the government to impose sanctions,
and so there is no incentive for those whose visas run out
to leave when they are meant to. It should be no surprise
that visa-overstaying such as moving here permanently
on a short stay visitors visa - is widely thought to be
the main form of illegal immigration to the UK.
The US, Canada, Australia and New Zealand all have complex,
tightly upheld, immigration procedures that require would-be
immigrants to prove among other things that
they are not criminals and do not have diseases that will
make them a threat to public health or a burden on the health
system. In contrast, despite the fact that immigration has
tripled the rate of HIV and doubled the rate of TB in Britain,
the UK has no health tests for would be immigrants. In fact,
the UK is now the only country in the world of primary immigration,
apart from Israel, that does not select between the seriously
sick and the healthy. Even in the heyday of mass immigration
to the US, the sick were turned away at Ellis Island.
Blair Fact 3:
In international terms, the
UK is not a particularly high migration country
Mr Blair points out that in the UK, only 8 % of the work
force is foreign born, compared to 15 % in the US and 25
% in Australia. He doesnt point out that the US is
only 12 % as densely populated as the UK, and Australia
1 %. In contrast to the UK, they are empty continents and
so can accept higher migration without the same quality
of life and housing impacts.
According to the International Organisation for Migration
in International Migration Report 2002, the
UK had a stock of 4.029 million migrants, exceeded only
by ten out of nearly 200 other countries in the world.
According to the IOM, in 2002 there were only five countries
in the world that actively encouraged primary immigration
as government policy: the US, Canada, Australia, New Zealand
and Israel. To this list, we can now add the UK as a result
of the governments U turn on the previous policy of
no primary immigration. The five all have one thing in common
they are young countries, which happened to be created
by Britain. They are all also empty lands with very low
population density, apart from Israel, which has a policy
of Jewish only immigration that would be incompatible with
European notions of non-discrimination. In other words,
the UK is the only mature, densely populated country in
the world that has a policy of actively encouraging mass
primary immigration.
The government likes to portray those who oppose its policy
of encouraging immigration as extremists. But those who
oppose the policy of actively encouraging mass immigration,
are only asking for a return to the immigration policy that
the UK has had for all but 20 of the last 2000 years, asking
for a similar immigration policy as every other EU country,
and a similar policy to all but 5 of the worlds nearly
200 countries.
In historic and contemporary global terms, it is the Blair
governments immigration policy that is extreme.
Fact 4:
Those who come here make a
huge contribution, particularly to our public services.
Mr Blair points out the very high proportion of immigrants
working in the National Health Service and in schools, and
reiterates the clearly true fact that much of Britains
public services would collapse if the immigrants who staffed
them suddenly disappeared. But he failed to point out this
was the inevitable results of thirty years of government
policy of employing cheap, willing immigrants rather than
improving pay and conditions so that Britain can train and
retain enough of its own workers. One third of trainee nurses
in Britain are so disheartened they leave the profession
before they qualify, and Britain has 100,000 fully qualified
nurses not working in nursing, more than enough to fill
any vacancies. Record numbers of British nurses are also
leaving the UK for better pay and conditions overseas.
The policy of refusing to improve pay and conditions to
the level needed to ensure that Britain supplies enough
of its own medical staff and teachers has two consequences.
It saves money for the British taxpayer, and it deprives
developing countries of staff they need more urgently than
Britain does, and which their even more impoverished tax
payers paid for the training of. If the fourth largest economy
in the world refuses to pay enough to ensure its own supply
of nurses and teachers, it guarantees a global shortage
of these mobile professions, from which the worlds
poorest countries are the guaranteed losers.
There is nothing inevitable about this. Other countries
with better funded health services, such as France and Germany,
have had good records of developing their own supply of
staff and dont rely nearly so heavily on immigrant
labour. The NHSs dependence on developing world labour
is an anomaly in the developed world.
The United Nations International Labour Organisation
perfectly described the self-defeating nature of British
government policy, and the flaw in Tony Blairs argument,
in its 2001 report Migration for the Benefit of All:
Towards a New Paradigm for Migrant Labour. It warned
that the policy lead to native flight from those
professions, led to migrant ghettoisation in
them, and ensured a short term labour shortage became a
long term one:
It is just a near certainty
that by targeting occupations which are already failing
to attract natives, such sectors have become even less attractive
to natives as wage growth is depressed relative to non-target
sectors. Since the occupations under recruitment for migrants
may provide one of the very few portals into the host economy,
migrants may conversely be expected to flock to these entry
occupations. These two effects, when taken in combination,
lead to the phenomenon of native flight which is sometimes
referred to as ghettoization. This is generally
seen as a problem for nations, which are striving for a
migrant presence to complement natives rather than displacing
them.
It continues:
As more migrants are targeted
on a particular field which is failing in its bid to attract
native workers, wages will increasingly fall short of competitive
offerings, causing an acceleration of native flight towards
non-targetted fields. This curious cycle is sometimes seen
as a native worker shortage, though the term
seems particularly ill suited to describe a problem of employers
which is ultimately self inflicted. What may in fact begin
as a simple temporary sport shortage of trained
native workers, can in fact be made considerably more permanent
by the attempting a quick fix from migrant labour. Any program
which imports migrants into a sector whose employers are
complaining of insufficient trained natives, can be expected
to exacerbate (rather than alleviate) its native shortage.
Rather than raising incentives to entice new workers to
seek training to fill the empty slots, visas are likely
to be used to avoid the needed market response
|